Production, Manufacturing and Logistics
Ensuring responsive capacity: How to contract with backup suppliers

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2010.05.044Get rights and content

Abstract

Firms that source from offshore plants frequently perceive the lack of reliability and flexibility to be among the major drawbacks of their strategy. To mitigate against imminent mismatches of uncertain supply and demand, establishing capacity hedges in the form of responsive backup suppliers is a way out that many firms follow. This article analyzes how firms should contract with backup suppliers, inducing the latter to install responsive capacity. We show that supply options are appropriate to achieve sourcing channel coordination under forced compliance, whereas any firm commitment contract imposes a deadweight loss on the system. Whereas price-only contracts are unable to coordinate the sourcing channel under voluntary compliance, utilization-dependent price-only contracts are. Under the former contract, a price-focused strategy on the part of the manufacturer turns out to diminish the system’s service level and possibly has negative implications on installed backup capacity, and not least on the manufacturer’s profit.

Introduction

Firms that offshore their sourcing activities typically face two potential drawbacks (Fraunhofer, 2008, PRTM, 2008). First, sourcing from offshore plants or suppliers curtails supply-side flexibility because the distance to supply sources increases either from a geographical, organizational, or cultural perspective. Long delivery times and lack of sourcing flexibility (PRTM, 2008), which is an antecedent of supply chain agility (Swafford et al., 2006), decreases one’s ability to respond to demand-side fluctuations (Christopher and Peck, 2004). Second, the comparatively low reliability of offshore plants in terms of delivery performance and product quality is an ongoing issue for a large number of supply chain or purchasing managers. Firms seek to balance the cost advantages that come with offshoring with the responsiveness of backup supply bases close to their operating sites. Relying on backup suppliers is one major strategy to mitigate (Chopra and Sodhi, 2004) against these diseconomies of vulnerability (Hayes et al., 2005). In other words, firms attempt to install operational hedges (Huchzermeier and Cohen, 1996) in the form of backup supply sources, enabling them to smooth out the two-sided supply and demand uncertainty they face.

However, being more costly, the responsive supplier is relegated to a backup role. He only comes into the operation if demand is greater than offshore supply. Provided that offshore sources are able to cover demand entirely, the manufacturer will give preference to the cheap offshore alternative and avoid costly responsive production. If, on the other hand, offshore production capabilities do not suffice to serve demand, the manufacturer critically relies on her responsive supplier in order to save severe mismatch costs. The question that arises is: How can the manufacturer ensure responsive capacity, given that the backup supplier is aware of his replacement function.

While firms in numerous industries – such as automotive (Sheffi, 2005), pharmaceuticals (Chopra et al., 2007), and electronics (Tomlin, 2006) – reap the benefits of responsive backup supply, little attention has been paid on how to contract for it. One contracting strategy is to compensate for backup deliveries with high prices upon large deliveries, as is practiced in the following example. Kolbus, a leading manufacturer of bookbinding machinery relies on a network of small suppliers located within 20 kilometre of its headquarters in Germany. Kolbus’s customers in the print industry demand quick delivery times of about 6 weeks; high service levels are among the most important sales points for this complex project business. The majority of parts are produced or purchased on a make-to-stock basis through in-house production or from offshore suppliers, respectively. In addition, for 70% of its purchased parts, Kolbus is connected to one alternative backup supplier close to its plant. Kolbus’s COO, states that “if we actually need the local suppliers as an extended workbench on a full scale, we compensate them for their deliveries generously. And they are prepared, still knowing that they cannot reckon on us for steadily incoming orders”.

In this article we analyze how a manufacturer should contract with her backup supplier to ensure responsive capacity and, at the same time, benefit from offshore sourcing. We investigate how the manufacturer can obtain a responsive capacity hedge against two-sided supply and demand uncertainty to achieve Pareto efficient alignment of the manufacturer’s offshore capacity and the backup supplier’s responsive capacity investments via contracting mechanisms. We consider several types of contracts that reflect different degrees of flexibility, including firm commitments, supply options, price-only strategies, and utilization-dependent price-only strategies. Designing a contract requires the manufacturer to account for the backup supplier’s awareness of his backup role. Being conscious about the manufacturer’s offshore investment option, the backup supplier has to decide on a relationship-specific investment (Williamson, 1985), that is, the installment of dedicated responsive capacity, before demand and offshore supply uncertainty materializes.

The remainder of this article is structured as follows. We review the literature in Section 2 and present our model in Section 3. The backup and offshore capacity investment and contracting games under both forced compliance and voluntary compliance regimes are studied in Section 4 for firm commitments, supply options, and price-only contracts. We present a simple utilization-dependent contract that coordinates the decentralized system under voluntary compliance in Section 5. We present our conclusions in Section 6.

Section snippets

Literature review

The research presented in this article is particularly connected to works in the fields of capacity contracting and random yield management. Cachon (2003) reviews the substantial literature on supply chain contracting. From the contracting point of view, our model is closely related to the models of Cachon and Lariviere, 2001, Van Mieghem, 1999. In both models, the downstream firm, referred to as the manufacturer, relies on capacity investments of an upstream firm, referred to as the supplier.

The model

Our contracting model considers a supply chain comprising a manufacturer and a backup supplier who both seek to maximize their expected profit. The timing of events is depicted in Fig. 1, notation is summarized in Table 1. The manufacturer offers a contract to the responsive backup supplier, who may accept or reject the offer. Reflecting the market power of the manufacturer, the offer has a take-it-or-leave-it character. The supplier’s reservation profit is normalized to zero. Thus, he will

Firm commitments, supply options, and price-only contracts

In this section, we extend the “full information scenario” of Cachon and Lariviere (2001) by endowing the manufacturer with a (cheap) offshore supply alternative; this relegates her responsive supplier to a backup role. The contract the manufacturer offers the backup supplier is assumed to consist of a number l  0 of firm commitments and a number o  0 of options. This combined contract type allows us to capture several other contract schemes such as buy-back contracts (Pasternack, 1985) and

Utilization-dependent compensation for backup supply

In this section, we will show how a simple utilization-dependent price-only contract can lead to supply chain coordination under voluntary compliance. A utilization-dependent wholesale price is a contract that maps responsive supply into a single price tariff payable per unit delivered; that is, the wholesale price w is a nonnegative function on the (state-dependent) transfer quantity qt. Moreover, we restrict our attention to the class of piecewise-linear (i.e., staircase function type)

Conclusion

The main question we addressed in this article is how a manufacturer can ensure responsive capacity by contracting with a backup supplier given that the manufacturer installs offshore capacity at the same time. Our findings highlight the importance of flexibility in contracts with backup suppliers. Under forced compliance, supply options are the most elegant way to achieve a channel optimal capacity portfolio of offshore and responsive capacity. With supply options, the manufacturer’s objective

References (31)

  • Stefan Minner

    Multiple-supplier inventory models in supply chain management: a review

    International Journal of Production Economics

    (2003)
  • Evan L. Porteus

    Stochastic inventory theory

  • Patricia M. Swafford et al.

    The antecedents of supply chain agility of a firm: scale development and model testing

    Journal of Operations Management

    (2006)
  • Volodymyr Babich

    Vulnerable options in supply chains: effects of supplier competition

    Naval Research Logistics

    (2006)
  • Gérard P. Cachon

    Supply chain coordination with contracts

  • Gérard P. Cachon et al.

    Contracting to assure supply: how to share demand forecasts in a supply chain

    Management Science

    (2001)
  • Sunil Chopra et al.

    The importance of decoupling recurrent and disruption risk in a supply chain

    Naval Research Logistics

    (2007)
  • Sunil Chopra et al.

    Managing risk to avoid supply-chain breakdown

    MIT Sloan Management Review Fall

    (2004)
  • Martin Christopher et al.

    Building the resilient supply chain

    International Journal of Business Logistics

    (2004)
  • Frank W. Ciarallo et al.

    A periodic review, production planning model with uncertain capacity and uncertain demand – optimality of extended myopic policies

    Management Science

    (1994)
  • Maqbool Dada et al.

    A newsvendor’s procurement problem when suppliers are unreliable

    Manufacturing and Service Operations Management

    (2007)
  • Karen Donohue

    Efficient supply contracts for fashion goods with forecast updating and two production modes

    Management Science

    (2000)
  • Fraunhofer, 2008. Production offshoring in reverse. Fraunhofer Institut System- und Innovationsforschung Press Release,...
  • Robert Hayes et al.

    Operations, Strategy, and Technology – Pursuing the Competitive Edge

    (2005)
  • Jack Hirshleifer

    On the economics of transfer pricing

    Journal of Business

    (1956)
  • Cited by (0)

    1

    Tel.: +49 2616509380; fax: +49 2616509389.

    View full text